Orrin Woodward on LIFE & Leadership

Inc Magazine Top 20 Leader shares his personal, professional, and financial secrets.

  • Orrin Woodward

    1
    Former Guinness World Record Holder for largest book signing ever, Orrin Woodward is a NY Times bestselling author of And Justice For All along with RESOLVED & coauthor of LeaderShift and Launching a Leadership Revolution. His books have sold over one million copies in the financial, leadership and liberty fields. RESOLVED: 13 Resolutions For LIFE made the Top 100 All-Time Best Leadership Books and the 13 Resolutions are the framework for the top selling Mental Fitness Challenge personal development program.

    Orrin made the Top 20 Inc. Magazine Leadership list & has co-founded two multi-million dollar leadership companies. Currently, he serves as the Chairman of the Board of the LIFE. He has a B.S. degree from GMI-EMI (now Kettering University) in manufacturing systems engineering. He holds four U.S. patents, and won an exclusive National Technical Benchmarking Award.

    This blog is an Alltop selection and ranked in HR's Top 100 Blogs for Management & Leadership.

  • Orrin’s Latest Book








  • 7 Day Free Access to Leadership Audios!

  • Email Me

  • NY Times Bestselling Book


  • Mental Fitness Challenge

  • Categories

  • Archives

Archive for the ‘Finances’ Category

Financial bondage is a form of slavery.

Scams, Coercion, & Networking

Posted by Orrin Woodward on November 11, 2010

This video describes me as a senior engineer at GM, working my way up the corporate ladder only to find it was leaning against the wrong wall. So glad I fell into Networking, Free Enterprise and Win-Win principles! Freedom is a leadership choice.[youtube http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=uNI–ULZ-dM]
I have spent the last several years studying the scams, schemes, and cons perpetrated on the American masses through the use of coercion.  As a multiple-time NY Times bestselling author, I cannot sit by idly and watch Americans lose their freedoms without speaking up. No scam can last unless backed by a monopoly of force/coercion.  Government is the only true monopoly of force available in any society.  Coercion requires force, which involves either government intervention or mafia type tactics.  Free enterprise businesses, like Network Marketing, cannot be a scam, since people are free to come and free to go, they will simply leave and the scam will collapse.  Government scams like social security, income taxes, and fiat money inflation, to name just a few, take advantage of the masses, since the masses are forced to participate against their will, whether their needs are being met or not.  Learning and defending American freedoms, against the encroachment of coercive government interventions, has become a key educational plank in my readings, writings and speeches of late.

[youtube http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vzKAe6mvjM4]

Scams coerce participation

If someone attempts a scam, without the power of coercion, it will not last.  For example, if someone attempted to sell a property for twice the market rate, perhaps a clueless customer would fall for it, but it couldn’t last as the market will quickly identify the offending party and avoid any business dealing with him.  But who can avoid business dealings with an all pervasive government?  Who can opt out of social security?  Who can opt out of excessive taxes?  Who can opt out of the government’s fiat money?  Scams require force to continue the scheme over the long term.  I have spent years of my life, studying and calling out scams to help educate Americans on the work cut out for us to eliminate the government supported scams through the American system of representative government.

In fact, Murray Rothbard, the late Dean of the Austrian School of Economics, the economics school with the best track record in predicting the effects of government intervention in free economies, stated:

But, above all, the crucial monopoly is the State’s control of the use of violence: of the police and armed services, and of the courts—the locus of ultimate decision-making power in disputes over crimes and contracts. Control of the police and the army is particularly important in enforcing and assuring all of the State’s other powers, including the all-important power to extract its revenue by coercion.

For there is one crucially important power inherent in the nature of the State apparatus. All other persons and groups in society (except for acknowledged and sporadic criminals such as thieves and bank robbers) obtain their income voluntarily: either by selling goods and services to the consuming public, or by voluntary gift (e.g., membership in a club or association, bequest, or inheritance). Only the State obtains its revenue by coercion, by threatening dire penalties should the income not be forthcoming. That coercion is known as “taxation,” although in less regularized epochs it was often known as “tribute.” Taxation is theft, purely and simply even though it is theft on a grand and colossal scale which no acknowledged criminals could hope to match. It is a compulsory seizure of the property of the State’s inhabitants, or subjects.

Many will call Network Marketing a scam, but unless backed by government coercion, meaning people are not free to leave, Networking cannot be a scam.  On the contrary, Networking is the purest example of free enterprise left in the Western world.  People win or lost on their efforts, not government protection of the profession. Wherever you see someone producing long term sustainable results in Networking, you know that a leader is building a winning culture that works. Networking has been around for well over sixty years, and scams cannot last that long unless backed by some form of government coercion. In Networking, some will win, and some will lose, but that simply defines life, not a scam. 

Gabriel Kolko, a New Left leaning historian, described why the US government intervened with business at the turn of the 20th century, “Ironically, contrary to the consensus of historians, it was not the existence of monopoly that caused the federal government to intervene in the economy,
but the lack of it.”

Big Businesses built huge Trust in each field, in an attempt to control market prices, squeezing extra profits from consumers in the scam, but it didn’t work. Big Business (Morgan, Rockefellers, etc), ended up running to Big Government,  using government’s monopoly of force to regulate industries and create extra profits for themselves.  This is a scam on every consumer in every field affected and why I cannot remain quiet.

I love my business relationship with Dallin Larsen and MonaVie, and I have friends in many other Networking companies. What I enjoy about our profession is the right for any company to create a better business model and compete in free enterprise.  There are no huge Trusts in Networking. Let the best company and community win period, without the aid of government to stack the deck in Big Businesses favor.  There are many great companies and leaders in Networking and the more we lift one another, the more the Networking tide rises for all in our profession. I don’t have to attack another enterprise in order to build my own. If you really believe in your Networking business, just build it, allowing your actions to speak louder than your words. Leaders will flock from around the world if you have truly created a better business model.  Any business that has been successful over the years, if not the decades, must be serving their customers in order to survive in a true free enterprise model.

Robert Kiyosaki – author of the #1 New York Times bestseller Rich Dad Poor Dad
Network marketing teaches basic, critical life skills. It teaches people how to overcome their fears, how to communicate, and how to handle rejection and maintain persistence. This kind of education is absolutely priceless.  Here’s what I tell people: “Even if you don’t like it, stay with it for five years and you’ll be better equipped to survive in the real world of business. And you’ll be a better person.” The people who are successful in network marketing have a spiritual cause. They genuinely want to help better others’ lives. If you don’t have that, if you just want a paycheck, then work for the post office!

Success isn’t easy, but then again, neither is failure

When people call the entire Network Marketing profession a scam, merely because they didn’t succeed, it demonstrates their lack of understanding of scams and personal responsibility.  No one should teach that success in Networking is easy, since it’s not, but failure certainly isn’t easy either.  Malcolm Gladwell, a best selling author, teaches that success in any field requires 10,000 hours of diligent study and action.  Anything less, and that person is still an amateur in his profession.  For someone to try Networking for several years, and then state it’s a scam, is simply a version of Aesop’s fables, sour grapes from an amateur fox who couldn’t reach the desired fruit.  For example, in high school, I wrestled in many tournaments.  I could not of imagined any wrestler calling the tournament a scam because he didn’t receive a medal.  The sour grapes wrestler would have been laughed out of the arena, since many do not win medals, not having at that moment, learned the skills and put in the hours to win at a tournament level.

Seth Godin is author of the New York Times bestsellers The Dip and Tribes
Network marketing works when it’s not about you. It works when it is about the customer. Not sort of about the customer as a way of helping you, not kinda about the customer when you imagine how they could act like you and become part of your downline. No, it works when it is generous and transparent and true. If someone buys from you because they are a friend or because it’s easier than avoiding you, that’s not about the customer. Here’s my dream for you: find a product and a price and a story that people choose to seek out. Discover a niche that people would miss if it disappeared. Offer an experience that’s about more than money, more than making a living and more than recruiting a new salesperson. When you bring joy and utility and trust to people (at a fair price), they’ll embrace you.

Anonymous Victims Online

In today’s society, people can write anonymously about their victimization, crying about their lack of results, claiming to be scammed from the Networkers (better wrestlers) who kicked their butts in free enterprise, while the victims claim it was rigged against them, even though others seem to be winning while they are whining.  If someone felt they were hurt, why not seek out the leaders of the company or community for resolution?  Doesn’t this sounds like the right thing, not to mention the honorable thing to do?  Rather than post anonymously, hiding their identities as well as their real motives, assaulting the reputations of people that they don’t personally know, why not call the community leaders or the company to get the issue resolved?  This is why anonymous blog postings hold no value with me. If someone doesn’t feel strong enough about his opinion to state his real name, then why should I give his opinion any credence at all?  Any reputable company would serve the customer in a heartbeat. I have personally been involved in several customer issues myself over the years, and they were amicably resolved.  I believe in customer satisfaction and have grown my business through the application of this principle consistently.  In fact, the TEAM initiated a email help system, similar to Amazon’s, to ensure all issues are resolved promptly.  If anyone leaves the TEAM unhappy, it wasn’t through lack of concern, but through lack of interest by the customer to address.  Perhaps, the real reason that many post in Networking are anonymous, postings that act as if they are upset at the company, are because they are from competitors, not real customers.  These are the bottom feeders of Networking, the parasite marketers, who, believing in a win-lose scarcity mentality, blatantly attack one company’s reputation for the alleged benefits supplied to their current company.  Sadly, this egregious behavior happens often, leading to much of the negative written online.  When the perceived opportunity for gain exceeds the applied character of those involved, parasite marketing will typically occur.

Free to Win & Free to Lose

In America, one is free to win, free to lose, and, even free to blame.  But unless one is forced against his will, a force that’s necessary for any real scam, one will look silly to blame his loss on anything but his own incompetence.  It’s foolish to blame others, who worked harder, applied themselves more, and developed the skills to win. Calling winners names, calling the tournament (profession) a scam, pointing fingers at others, all in an effort to salve a wounded pride.  This may take the focus off off his lack of skills temporarily, but it reveals more about the character of the sender of the toxic message than the receiver’s character.  It seems that ‘passing the buck’ is endemic in today’s society, but one of the goals of the Networking is to teach people personal responsibility.  Accepting responsibility is the beginning of all leadership growth. In Networking, unless the person was forced to attend meetings against his will, forced to buy materials without a buy back provision, why is he passing judgment on others for his lack of results?  The minute you blame others for your failures is the minute you surrender responsibility for your own life.  In the Team, we teach that freedom is a gift and we support your freedom to win, lose or leave, voting with your own feet.  The tens of thousands who are part of TEAM, were not coerced into joining, but joined freely by buying into the leadership culture.  The TEAM leaders win by serving customers, not controlling them, even offering a 30 day, no questions asked, 100% return policy for any items purchased.  No business would be foolish enough to publicly state that, unless they knew that 99.99% plus of their customers were happily served. All reputable Networking companies in our profession offer similar refund policies.

Stephen M.R. Covey is author of the New York Times bestseller The Speed of Trust
To me, the most interesting dimension of network market-ing is the focus on building relationships of trust. All parties must be able to trust one an- other, or nothing moves forward. Accountability, transparency and other high-trust behaviors clearly flow out of your character and competence, which in turn help to improve, solidify and create better relationships. Those relationships are powerful fruits that enable you to enjoy greater collaboration, a better reputation and shared accomplishment. When done well, network marketing is the speed of trust in action.

[youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=3rtQ-IVcvAo&w=480&h=385]

Team – Leadership Development Engine

My friend, John Maxwell, a top selling leadership guru, teaches that everything rises and falls on leadership.  In my business ventures, I have focused on improving people’s leadership levels, thus improving their results.  The many success stories achieved from this approach boggles the mind.  Literally thousands of couples have reduced debts, improved relationships, and freed up their time from the mundane tasks, to focus on the important ones, by applying the principles learned from the TEAM leadership system.  Does everyone get wealthy?  Of course not, not everyone will discipline themselves daily to achieve that level of success.  The key point is that those who do apply themselves, do achieve success.  Similarly, those who don’t apply themselves consistently have no right to blame TEAM for their lack of discipline or poor thinking. Dan & Lisa Hawkins, a mechanic and day care provider, Chris & Danae Mattis, a counselor and dance instructor, and Marc & Kristine Miletello, both teachers, to name just a few of the TEAM leaders, all started from different walks of life, but all have achieved success through changing their associations and their thinking.  Instead of sharing their stories for them, I let them speak for themselves in the following YouTube videos.

[youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=32iwvGzGpgs&w=640&h=385]

Two of the Top 30 Leaders in the World

The most recent Top 30 list of leadership gurus has Chris Brady, my co-author of the number one Wall Street Journal best seller for two weeks in a row – Launching a Leadership Revolution, and myself as Top 30 Leadership Gurus, making TEAM the only organization in the world with two of the Top 30.  Gladwell’s 10,000 hours sure paid off for both Brady and myself.  After five years, neither one of us had much success in Networking, but instead of quitting we chose to improve, leading to tens of thousands of satisfied customers.  One either hates losing enough to change or one hates changing enough to lose.  Brady and I chose to improve, as we hate losing, others may choose quitting, as they hate changing.  I support their choices, because I support the freedom to choose. Giving people the freedom to make their own decisions, and the freedom to live with the subsequent results is the American way.  If you win, you get the credit, but correspondingly, if you lose, you must take the blame.  This is what made America great, and what my parents, along with competitive sports taught me as a young boy.  No leader is good enough to make someone win against their will.  In the TEAM, we commit to providing the best leadership training available for the dollar invested, but you must commit to the personal growth and the actions necessary to convert the training into results. People like Hawkins, Mattis, and Miletello applied the principles and changed their lives.  What you will do, is up to you.

[youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=16BGmUCV16U&w=640&h=390]

What Scams have I studied to date?
If you found this site looking for my research into the coercion based scams that I have studied so far, here is a partial list to get started.

1. Social Security Scam
2. Fiat Money Scam
3. Tariff Scam
4. Democracy Scam
5. National Bank Scam
6. U.N. Scam

God Bless, Orrin Woodward

Posted in Finances, Freedom/Liberty | 3 Comments »

The Origins of Fiat Money in the West

Posted by Orrin Woodward on November 8, 2010

The following history of money was learned by reading my new favorite economist, Murray Rothbard.  His History of Money is a mighty tome, which will scare many readers off, but has so many nuggets in it, that I felt led to summarize just a portion on this blog. I want to personally thank the Mises Institute for providing access to Rothbard’s works.  Here is my summary of the beginning of fiat paper money in the West.  All factual details were pulled from Rothbard’s ground breaking research.   

Outside of the medieval Chinese, who invented both paper and printing hundreds of years before the West, colonial Massachusetts was the first government to issue fiat paper money.  In fact, the colonial Americans were the reigning experts on fraudulent paper money issues, backed by nothing more than the misplaced trust the colonist had for their state governments.  The dismal monetary history began with a failed plundering expedition against the French colony of Quebec.  The Massachusetts government had grown accustomed to victorious raids against Quebec, typically paying the colonial recruits out of the proceeds lifted from the defeated French.  But in 1690, the New England colonials were defeated, causing a small problem for Massachusetts, but a huge problem for West.  The lesson learned by local colonial New England politicians have been co-opted by money hungry politicians of today, making fiat money the standard operating procedure out of every financial mess caused by over promising and under delivery bureaucrats in Washington.  See the chart below, that I found online, displaying the alarming drop in the purchasing power of the USA dollar through fiat monetary policies.

Dollar pictureThe soldiers arrived back in Boston ill tempered, demanding payment of their money, regardless of the outcome of the raid.  Hosting discontented soldiers with weapons, along with the will to use them, in the city was not an enjoyable sight for Boston citizens.  Rejected in an attempt to raise the funds from local merchants, the governmental leaders struck upon an idea that still echos through society.  Massachusetts concluded that printing £7,000 of paper notes, using them to pay the soldiers, was safer than having soldier unpaid within the city.  Concerned that the public would not accept the paper, the government made several pledges in an attempt to alleviate the public’s suspicion.  First, that it would redeem the paper notes in gold or silver out of tax revenues over the next couple of years, and second, that no more notes would be issued.  Not surprisingly, both parts of the pledge were disregarded as fast as government politicians could say, “Free Money.”  The bills went unredeemed for over forty years, while other notes were issued when money was needed.  It took less than four months for more notes to be issued, ignoring the pledge wholesale in government’s greed for free funds.  By February of 1691, another £40,000 of unbacked paper notes was issued to make up for a shortage of government funds, politicians proclaiming boldly, and falsely, that this would be the last issue of notes.

Massachusetts had stumbled across the SFN (Something For Nothing) formula, and not withstanding the number of pledges to stop issuing notes, the local politicians were like kids running loose in a candy store while the owner sleeps behind the counter.  Government induced fiat paper inflation was born and bred upon the shores of America.    The increasing supply of paper money, along with the growing lack of confidence in the paper, since it wasn’t backed by anything, but the level of trust colonist had in the local politicians, depreciated by over 40 percent, as compared to the gold and silver specie (coins). Like all governments, when they are busted with their hands in the candy, Massachusetts used force to make the “greedy”, “traitorous”, merchants take paper on par with specie.  This simply kicked in Gresham’s law, driving real money underground, while everyone bought and sold using paper (no better than Parker Bros Monopoly money) in the New England economy.  Citizens are not stupid, why use real specie, when paper money is worth 40 percent less and other citizens are forced, by law, to take it on par with gold and silver specie.  The corresponding shortage of coins drove more of the egregious behavior that caused the inflation in the first place.  Over £240,000 of paper money was issued by 1711, but during the same time, specie had all but disappeared.  The shortage of gold and silver didn’t cause the need for paper money, but the paper money enacted Gresham’s law, which caused the predictable shortage of specie.

I will save you the blow by blow details, offered in Rothbard’s book, of Massachusetts further inflationary printing of paper issues, but needless to say, New England government leaders did not prove trustworthy.  Learning the history of  fiat paper issues in Colonial America should be enough to scare all American citizens into demanding gold backed dollars, but sadly, few are willing to learn from history.  The British Crown, finally intervened, halting the mad rush into insolvency, caused by SFN paper induced fever suffered by local New England government leaders.  But before the British intervened, from 1744 to 1748, paper money expanded from, are you ready for this, £300,000 to £2.5 million! The depreciation of Massachusetts money was to such an extent that silver had risen to over sixty shillings an ounce, over ten times the price that it sold before the ‘paper money mania.’

There is much more to say on inflation and the purposeful depreciation of the American dollar for the benefit of Washington bureaucrats, but I will save it for another day.  Just one question before I end, “Do you think today’s politicians are more trustworthy than the local Massachusetts politicians were in their day?”  If you answer the question the same way that I did (a resounding no), then why do we allow the Federal Reserve to do the dirty work of today’s politicians?  In an obvious effort to subvert the direct printing of fiat money by government, through the use of a Federal Reserve (that isn’t federal, and has no reserves), but merely prints the money for our bureaucrats and loans it back to our government at taxpayers expense, government is bilking its citizens that it should be protecting.  Some may wonder why I bother to read this stuff, let alone share it with others, but I believe my duty is clear; wherever there is injustice, and I sit back and do nothing, I become an enabler to that injustice.  My conscience will not allow me to sit back and do nothing, hopefully, others similarly endowed with conscience, will educate themselves and the injustice will end. God Bless, Orrin Woodward

Posted in Finances | 4 Comments »

Ludwig Von Mises – Morals over Money

Posted by Orrin Woodward on October 27, 2010

Character is not a binary switch, meaning one cannot divide people into two Manichean groups, one with character and the other without.  Instead, think of character, less like an on/off switch and more like the spectrum of colors.  A few people having little to no character, a few others, having character that cannot be bought, while the masses fall into a spectrum of character, having a portion of character, moving from a little to a lot.  The more character someone has, the harder it is to buy them out, resisting offers of rewards or punishments intended to bend their character to comply with the wishes of the exploiters in life.  Most people have a price, yielding their character at that point, surrendering their principles to their pocketbooks and peace.  But a few, only a courageous few, will hold onto their principles, withstanding vociferous criticism, eschewing lucrative financial gains, no matter what to maintain their character.   Although few in number, they appear regularly on the stages of history, standing for their convictions, regardless of the price to be paid.  Whether one agrees with their stand or not, everyone should respect their convictions.  Imagine history without the likes of St. Paul, Augustine, Martin Luther, George Washington, Adam Smith, Ludwig Von Mises, Martin Luther King Jr., and Mother Theresa, to name just a few.  History is altered when men and women of character refuse to surrender at any price, valuing living authentic lives based upon their deepest principles, rather than receive the applause of the world, while knowing that they have sold out.  Standing for justice regardless of the strength of the opposition or the personal cost entailed in the stand is not for the weak of heart.   Thankfully, even though few in number, others, with the same convictions, but less courage, discerning the truthfulness of the stand, will rally around the leader, creating a movement that changes the course of history.  

Mises pictureLet’s review one such life,  a man by the name of Ludwig Von Mises, an economic leader who stood for truth in an era when most economist stumbled over themselves bowing to a lie.  There is an old saying, “Any dead fish can float downstream, but it takes a live one to swim against the current.” Mises swam against the currents, defending free enterprise and classic liberalism when nearly all were chasing after the perks offered by teaching government intervention and control.  Many other economist intellectually understood the errors in the Keynesian policies, knowing in there heart and minds that government spending sprees would only lead to massive debt and unemployment, but willingly surrendered their convictions for personal advancement during the Keynesian bubble turned train wreck.  Mises, a one man band against his profession initially, refused to go along with the charade, pointing out the logical fallacies, calculating the long term consequences, influencing other economist not to sell their minds for money and prestige.  Mises, a prototypical example of a man without a price, lived his life by the motto from Virgil, the Roman poet who wrote, “Tu ne cede malis sed contra audentior ito,” meaning, “do not give in to evil, but proceed ever more boldly against it.”  Mises proceeded to do just that for the duration of his long life.

In fact, Murray Rothbard, one of the great economists and minds of the twentieth century wrote of Mises:

Holding these views, and hewing to truth indomitably in the face of a century increasingly devoted to statism and collectivism, Mises became famous for his “intransigence” in insisting on a non-inflationary gold standard and on laissez-faire.

Effectively barred from any paid university post in Austria and later in the United States, Mises pursued his course gallantly. As the chief economic adviser to the Austrian government in the 1920s, Mises was single-handedly able to slow down Austrian inflation; and he developed his own “private seminar” which attracted the out­standing young economists, social scientists, and philosophers throughout Europe. As the founder of the “neo-Austrian School” of economics, Mises’s business cycle theory, which blamed inflation and depressions on inflationary bank credit encouraged by Central Banks, was adopted by most younger economists in England in the early 1930s as the best explanation of the Great Depression.

At a time when the stream was flowing to Statism, whether in the form Nazism, Fascism, Socialism, or Communism or the New Deal, Mises had overcome the hysteria of the times to think deeply on the underlying issues.  Rothbard again, shares Mises contributions in the following way:

For Mises was able to demonstrate (a) that the expansion of free markets, the division of labor, and private capital investment is the only possible path to the prosperity and flourishing of the human race; (b) that socialism would be disastrous for a modern economy because the absence of private ownership of land and capital goods prevents any sort of rational pricing, or estimate of costs, and (c) that government intervention, in addition to hampering and crippling the market, would prove counter-productive and cumulative, leading inevitably to socialism unless the entire tissue of interventions was repealed.

As I write this in 2010, after years of inflationary government policies, causing government debt to reach unsustainable levels, with socialistic thinking engendered into the masses through a school system funded by our Statist bureaucrats, Mises looks like a prophet.  Few will ever understand the courage it must have required of Mises to sustain such personal and professional animosity, all the while, believing that time would prove him right, knowing that truth is more important than professional perks. In fact Robert Heilbroner, a famous economist, more of the socialists flavor, but honest in his research of the data, in his article conceding the defeat of socialism to free enterprise, titled, The World After Communism, concluded:

But what spokesman of the present generation has anticipated the demise of socialism or the “triumph of capitalism”? Not a single writer in the Marxian tradition! Are there any in the left centrist group? None I can think of, including myself. As for the center itself—the Samuelsons, Solows, Glazers, Lipsets, Bells, and so on—I believe that many have expected capitalism to experience serious and mounting, if not fatal, problems and have anticipated some form of socialism to be the organizing force of the twenty-first century.

… Here is the part hard to swallow. It has been the Friedmans, Hayeks, von Miseses, e tutti quanti who have maintained that capitalism would flourish and that socialism would develop incurable ailments. Mises called socialism “impossible” because it has no means of establishing a rational pricing system; Hayek added additional reasons of a sociological kind (“the worst rise on top”). All three have regarded capitalism as the “natural” system of free men; all have maintained that left to its own devices capitalism would achieve material growth more successfully than any other system.

Heilbroner confronted the socialistic demise in the late 1980’s, not by diverting people’s attention, not by making excuses, but by honestly admitting that Mises, and his followers, were right all along.  I respect Heilbroner for calling out the ‘elephant in the room‘ avoided today’s Statists oriented economists.  The socialist/statist economist and politicians were wrong, even when a million of them called untruth the truth, it doesn’t alter the real truth.   Mises and his small band of rascals, although deprived of honors and recognition in their lifetime (with the exception of Hayek’s Nobel Prize the year after Mises death, probably in deference to the recently fallen defender of free enterprise), stood for truth and time has proven them right.  Government intervention, far from being a modern day elixir, has damaged economies and markets wherever its poison has been imbibed.  Sadly, once an untruth sinks into the consciousness of the body politic, rooting out the cancer can be a long term process.  As Mises stated in his magnum opus, Human Action, “Economics deals with society’s fundamental problems; it concerns everyone and belongs to all. It is the main and proper study of every citizen.”  All citizens should study the history of political, economic and spiritual freedoms, the very freedoms that under-gird all of our liberties enjoyed today.

One might be thinking, if Mises pointed out the fallacies of bank inflations and socialism as early as the 1920’s, why did we proceed for nearly a century on a spending binge, resulting in the near bankruptcy of most governments in the West?  The answer revolves around character, or, more precisely, lack of character.  ‘Follow the money’ – FTM, is the main principle that modern day politicians use to justify their egregious behaviors.  FTM along with it’s brother SFM – ‘something for nothing’ combine to make a powerful force, overcoming principles and character wherever they are allowed to prosper unchecked.  Since most people have a price, referring back to the spectrum of character,  educators and politicians FTM’d into supporting Keynesian policies, rationalizing their sell out, by the pot of gold at the end of the rainbow, offered to all willing to following the current.  The current that Mises opposed in his battle for truth against the modern currents.  Exploiters love something for nothing and will follow the money to determine their current convictions, no pun intended.   Meaning, that sadly, most people’s convictions are arrived at by following the external currents, not by, following their internal character.  FTM may sound cynical, but no professional in the historical or economic fields, interpreting historical events properly, can accurately understand motives and methods without thinking through FTM.   Since few can withstand the heady effects of money, power and prestige, FTM is usually the best indicator in studying the world’s actions.  Outside of the a select few like Mises, the minority character centered individuals, FTM is nearly a fool proof method in economic and historical studies.  But how are both educators and politicians rewarded for supporting faulty Keynesian economics?

Let’s start with the politicians, and what they gain by FTM and SFM.  Politicians, especially in modern day democracies, are constantly in need of at least two things.  The first being money.  If politicians had a way to tax the people without having to announce an unpopular tax increase, they would think they had died and gone to political heaven.  Keynesian economic thought made this heaven come to earth, by morally justifying, what previously had been verboten.  Keynesians taught that, by inflating the money supply, reaping the benefit of paper money not backed by gold or any other real wealth, at the expense of the masses by lowered value of their money, politicians could enjoy more money and power while maintaining popularity in office.  Keynesian’s provided an amenable world-view for politicians, condoning their SFM tendencies through inflationary money policies (read: a secret tax on the citizen’s money) without having to risk an election day disaster, proclaiming to all that they didn’t raise taxes.  Instead they applied a secret tax (worse than income tax in certain cases) applied through inflating the money supply. Since it’s not understood by the mass of people, politicians, hiding behind the Keynesian mantra, pass along to future citizens, citizens that the current politician doesn’t need to pander to, in order maintain peace with current electorate.  Like John Maynard Keynes, the economic systems founder, when fighting back against the rational economist, who pointed out the logical long run fallacies of Keynes’ proposals, stated, “In the long run, we are all dead.”  Perhaps a funny quip to confound the people, belying the immorality of modern economic methods by providing politicians with free money at posterities expense.

The economist, on the other hand, benefit from the prestige gained by supporting the immoral Keynesian policies.  It would take an individual of Mises like character, to withstand the promises of advancement, by supporting the Keynesian theories of government intervention throughout the economy.  Why do universities support government intervention?  Can you say FTM?  Who is funding nearly all the universities in America and the Western world?  Government anyone?  Statist Government?  The very government, who partners with educators to convince the masses on the benefit of inflationary and socialistic methods, then rewards the same educators by money grants, by prestigious university posts, and by government advisory roles in the Statist government created by said propaganda.  If you follow the money, it flows something like this in a simplistic rendition: government prints paper money, stealing value from all Americans, takes some of money to reward economist educators (I use that word loosely), who write mighty tomes (propaganda) in support of said governments, creating a virtuous cycle of advancement for exploiters in both the political and educational fields.  All of these benefits paid for at the expense of the masses, who being ignorant of the scheme, merely wonder why it becomes tougher every year to make a living.  Politicians win by spending money that isn’t theirs; economists win by receiving advancements by teaching untruths; the citizens lose by swallowing the lie, surrendering ‘we the people’ to ‘we the exploited.‘  The losses endured come in several forms.  First by having the value of their hard earned dollars reduced yearly, forcing people on fixed incomes to go back to work or seek government handouts, selling their freedoms in the bargain, the dollars loses value every year.  Second, the citizens are filled with propaganda on the benefits of Statist interventions, even though, after five thousand years of recorded history, socialism/statist policies have never worked.  This reminds me of the Kings of  Statist policies, Hitler and Lenin.  Hitler, that master manipulator through propaganda said, “Make the lie big, make it simple, keep saying it, and eventually they will believe it.”  How about this classic from Hitler as well, “How fortunate for leaders that men do not think.”  Not to be outdone, Lenin said, “A lie told often enough becomes truth.”  If economists are rewarded for following the company line, and the companies in this case is funded by the government, then it doesn’t take a grand conspiracy, but merely an understanding FTM and SFM, to see why our present economy is failing.  It’s hard for anyone to stand in the workplace, especially, if the boss rewards certain behaviors, while punishing others, leaving people in a moral quandary, pitting their money against their morals.
We have surrendered economic truth to the peace and
affluence of the elites all at the expense of the mass of citizens.   It
is time for a group of men and women, like our founding fathers, to
stand for truth, no matter where it leads.  If everyone continues the
charade parade, society as a whole is the loser.  Even those who benefit
in the short term will lose when the system collapses.  Whether you are
a Republican, a Democrat, a Libertarian, an Independent, or undecided,
you have a vested interested in weeding out the intoxicating effect that
SFM and FTM have over our body politic.  God only knows the future
course of our country, but let it not be written, in the hour of need,
that our great country was abandoned by leaders, who lacked the courage
and character to make a stand.  Millions of men and women will surrender
to untruth, the subsequent lies engulfing the world in darkness, but
when one courageous person has had enough, one person, be it man or
woman, who being sick and tired of the lies and darkness, lights a match
inside his soul with truth, scattering the darkness of the millions by
the light cast from one soul set burning brightly on the oil of truth!
Where is the next generation of men and women, willing to set there soul
on fire for truth?  People, who, as Mises life motto from Virgil said,
“do not give in to evil, but proceed ever more boldly against it.”  God
Bless, Orrin Woodward

Posted in Finances | 1 Comment »

Economics and History – Austrian Theory

Posted by Orrin Woodward on October 18, 2010

Sitting down to read one of my favorite authors (Murray Rothbard), I stumbled across a description of the Austrian School
difference that stunned me, being the best description of the Austrian School Theory of History and Economics that I have ever read.  Dr.Joseph Salerno, who wrote this essay, is a professor at Pace University and delivers a powerful essay on Ludwig Von Mises and Murray Rothbard in this introduction to Rothbard’s book on banking.  If you would like to understand why economics matters more today than ever before, being concerned with the failure of modern day economic messiahs, then this portion of Salerno’s essay is for you.  Leadership matters and you are only qualified to lead in fields in which you have mastered the materials.  History, Economics and Leadership go hand in hand if you plan on making a difference in our world today.  Enjoy the article and please share your thoughts. 

God Bless,

Orrin Woodward

Rothbard’s approach to monetary history does not focus on measurement but on motives. Once the goals of the actors and their ideas about the appropriate means for achieving these goals have been established, economic theory, along with other sciences, is brought to bear to trace out the effects of these actions in producing the complex events and processes of history which are only partially and imperfectly captured in statistical data. This is not to say that Rothbard ignores the quantitative aspects of historical monetary processes. Indeed, his book abounds with money, price, and output data; but these data are always interpreted in terms of the
motivations of those who have contributed to their formation. For Rothbard, a particular price datum is, no less than the Spanish-American War, a  historical event,  and its causes must be traced back to the subjective aims governing human plans and choices.

In flatly rejecting the positivist approach to economic history, Rothbard adopts the method of historical research first formulated by Ludwig von Mises. In developing this method, Mises correctly delineated, for the first time, the relationship between theory and history. It is Rothbard’s great contribution in this volume—and his earlier  America’s Great Depression —to be the first to consistently apply it to economic history. It is worth summarizing this method here for several reasons. First, Mises’s writings on the proper method of historical research have inexplicably been almost completely ignored up to the present, even by those who have adopted Mises’s praxeological approach in economics. Second, familiarity with Mises’s method of historical research illuminates the source and character of the remarkable distinctiveness of Rothbard’s historical writings. In particular, it serves to correct the common but mistaken impression that Rothbard’s historical writings, especially on the origin and development of the U.S. monetary system, are grounded in nothing more substantial than an idiosyncratic “conspiracy theory of history.” Third, it gives us an opportunity to elucidate the important elaboration of Mises’s method that Rothbard contributed and which he deploys to great effect in explicating the topic of this volume. And finally, we find in Mises’s method a definitive refutation of the positivist’s claim that it is impossible to acquire real knowledge of subjective phenomena like human motives and that, therefore, economic history must deal exclusively with observable and measurable phenomena.

To begin with, Mises grounds his discussion of historical method on the insight that ideas are the primordial stuff of history. In his words:

“History is the record of human action. Human action is the conscious effort of man to substitute more satisfactory conditions for less satisfactory ones. Ideas determine what are to be considered more and less satisfactory conditions and what means are to be resorted to to alter them. Thus ideas are the main theme of the study of history.”

This is not to say that all history should be intellectual history, but that ideas are the ultimate cause of all social phenomena, including and especially economic phenomena. As Mises puts it.

“The genuine history of mankind is the history of ideas. It is ideas that distinguish man from all other beings. Ideas engender social institutions, political changes, technological methods of production, and all that is called economic conditions.”

Thus, for Mises, history:

“establishes the fact that men, inspired by definite ideas, made definite judgments of value, chose definite ends, and resorted to definite means in order to attain the ends chosen, and it deals furthermore with the outcome of their actions, the state of affairs the action brought about.”

Ideas—specifically those embodying the purposes and values that direct action—are not only the point of contact between history and economics, but differing attitudes toward them are precisely what distinguish the methods of the two disciplines. Both economics and history deal with individual choices of ends and the judgments of value underlying them. On the one hand, economic theory as a branch of praxeology takes these value judgments and choices as given data and restricts itself to logically inferring from them the laws governing the valuing and pricing of the means or “goods.” As such, economics does not inquire into the individual’s motivations in valuing and choosing specific ends. Hence, contrary to the positivist method, the truth of economic theorems is substantiated apart from and without reference to specific and concrete historical experience. They are the conclusions of logically valid deduction from universal experience of the fact that humans adopt means that they believe to be appropriate in attaining ends that they judge to be valuable.

The subject of history, on the other hand, “is action and the judgments of value directing action toward definite ends.”!” This means that for history, in contrast to economics, actions and value judgments are not ultimate “givens” but, in Mises’s words, “are the
starting point of a specific mode of reflection, of the specific understanding of the historical sciences of human action.” Equipped with the method of “specific understanding,” the historian, “when faced with a value judgment and the resulting action . . . may try to understand how they originated in the mind of the actor, ”it is true that in deriving theorems that apply to the specific conditions characterizing human action in our world, a few additional facts of a lesser degree of generality are inserted into the deductive chain of reasoning. These include the facts that there exists a variety of natural resources, that human labor is differentiated, and that leisure is valued as a consumer’s good.

The difference between the methods of economics and history may be illustrated with the following example. The economist qua economist “explains” the Vietnam War-era inflation that began in the mid-1960s and culminated in the inflationary recession of 1973-1975 by identifying those actions of the Fed with respect to the money supply that initiated and sustained it. The historian, including the economic historian, however, must identify and then assign weights to all those factors that motivated  the various members of the Fed’s Board of Governors (or of the Federal Open Market Committee) to adopt this course
of action. These factors include: ideology; partisan politics; pressure exerted by the incumbent administration; the grasp of economic theory; the expressed and perceived desires of the Fed’s constituencies, including commercial bankers and bond dealers; the informal power and influence of the Fed chairman within the structure of governance; and so on.

In short, the economic historian must supply the motives underlying the actions that are relevant to explaining the historical event. And for this task, his only suitable tool is understanding. Thus, as Mises puts it.

“The scope of understanding is the mental grasp of phenomena which cannot be totally elucidated by logic, mathematics, praxeology, and the natural sciences to the extent that they cannot be cleared up by all these sciences.”

To say that a full explanation of any historical event, including an economic one, requires that the method of specific understanding be applied is not to diminish the importance of pure economic theory in the study of history. Indeed, as Mises points out, economics provides in its field a consummate interpretation of past events recorded and a consummate anticipation of the effects to be expected from future actions of a definite kind. Neither this interpretation nor this anticipation tells anything about the actual content and quality of the actual individuals’ judgments of value. Both presuppose that the individuals are valuing and acting, but their theorems are independent of and unaffected by the particular characteristics of this valuing and acting.

For Mises, then, if the historian is to present a complete explanation of a particular event, he must bring to bear not only his “specific
understanding” of the motives of action but the theorems of economic science as well as those of the other “aprioristic,” or non-experimental, sciences, such as logic and mathematics. He must also utilize knowledge yielded by the natural sciences, including the applied sciences of technology and therapeutics. Familiarity with the teachings of all these disciplines is required in order to correctly identify the causal relevance of a particular action to a historical event, to trace out its specific consequences, and to evaluate its success from the point of view of the actor’s goals.

For example, without knowledge of the economic theorem that, ceteris paribus, changes in the supply of money cause inverse changes in its purchasing power, a historian of the price inflation of the Vietnam War-era probably would ignore the Fed and its motives altogether. Perhaps, he is under the influence of the erroneous Galbraithian doctrine of administered prices with its implication of cost-push inflation.  In this case, he might concentrate exclusively and irrelevantly on the motives of union leaders
in demanding large wage increases and on the objectives of the “technostructure” of large business firms in acceding to these demands and deciding what part of the cost increase to pass on to consumers. Thus, according to Mises,

“If what these disciplines [i.e., the aprioristic and the natural sciences] teach is insufficient or if the historian chooses an erroneous theory out of several conflicting theories held by the specialists, his effort is misled and his performance is abortive.” But what exactly is the historical method of specific understanding, and how can it provide true knowledge of a wholly subjective and unobservable phenomenon like human motivation? First of all, as Mises emphasizes, the specific understanding of past
events is not a mental process exclusively resorted to by historians. It is applied by everybody in daily intercourse with all his fellows. It is a technique employed in all interhuman relations. It is practiced by children in the nursery and kindergarten, by businessmen in trade, by politicians and statesmen in affairs of state. All are eager to get information about other people’s valuations and plans and to appraise them correctly!

The reason this technique is so ubiquitously employed by people in their daily affairs is because all action aims at rearranging future conditions so that they are more satisfactory from the actor’s point of view. However, the future situation that actually emerges always depends partly on the purposes and choices of others besides the actor. In order to achieve his ends, then, the actor must
anticipate not only changes affecting the future state of affairs caused by natural phenomena, but also the changes that result from the conduct of others who, like him,  are  contemporaneously planning  and  acting. Understanding the values and goals of others is thus an inescapable prerequisite for successful action.

Now, the method that provides the individual planning action with information about the values and goals of other actors is essentially the same method employed by the historian who seeks knowledge of the values and goals of actors in bygone epochs. Mises emphasizes the universal application of this method by referring to the actor and the historian as “the historian of the future” and “the historian of the past,” respectively. Regardless of the purpose for which it is used, therefore, understanding aims at establishing the facts that men attach a definite meaning to the state of their environment, that they value this state and, motivated by these judgments of value, resort to definite means in order to preserve or to attain a definite state of affairs different from that which would prevail if they abstained from any purposeful reaction. Understanding deals with judgments of value, with the choice of ends and of the means resorted to for the attainment of these ends, and with the valuation of the outcome of actions per-formed.

Furthermore, whether directed toward planning action or interpreting history, the exercise of specific understanding is not an arbitrary or haphazard enterprise peculiar to each individual historian or actor; it is the product of a discipline that Mises calls “thymology,” which encompasses “knowledge of human valuations and volitions.” Mises characterizes this discipline as
follows:

“Thymology is on the one hand an offshoot of introspection and on the other a precipitate of historical experience. It is what everybody learns from intercourse with his fellows. It is what a man knows about the way in which people value different conditions, about their wishes and desires and their plans to realize these wishes and desires. It is the knowledge of the social environment in which a man lives and acts or, with historians, of a foreign milieu about which he has learned by studying special sources.”

Thus, Mises tells us, thymology can be classified as “a branch of history” since “[i]t derives its knowledge from historical experience.” Consequently, the epistemic product of thymo-logical experience is categorically different from the knowledge derived from experiments in the natural sciences. Experimental knowledge consists of “scientific facts” whose truth is independent of time. Thymological knowledge is confined to “historical facts,” which are unique and non-repeatable events. Accordingly, Mises concludes,

All that thymology can tell us is that in the past definite men or groups of men were valuing and acting in a definite way. Whether they will in the future value and act in the same way remains uncertain. All that can be asserted about their future conduct is speculative anticipation of the future based on specific understanding of the historical branches of the sciences of human action. . . . What thymology achieves is the elaboration of a catalogue of human traits. It can moreover establish the fact that certain traits appeared in the past as a rule in connection with certain other traits.”

More concretely, all our anticipations about how family members, friends, acquaintances, and strangers will react in particular situations are based on our accumulated thymological experience. That a spouse will appreciate a specific type of jewelry for her birthday, that a friend will enthusiastically endorse our plan to see a Clint Eastwood movie, that a particular student will complain
about his grade—all these expectations are based on our direct experience of their past modes of valuing and acting. Even our
expectations of how strangers will react in definite situations or what course political, social, and economic events will take are based on thymology. For example, our reservoir of thymological experience provides us with the knowledge that men are jealous of their wives. Thus, it allows us to “understand” and forecast that if a man makes overt advances to a married woman in the presence of her husband, he will almost certainly be rebuffed and runs a considerable risk of being punched in the nose. Moreover, we may forecast with a high degree of certitude that both the Republican and the Democratic nominees will outpoll the Libertarian Party candidate in a forthcoming presidential election; that the price for commercial time during the televising of the Major League Soccer championship will not exceed the price for commercials during the broadcast of the Super Bowl next year; that the average price of a personal computer will be neither $1 million nor $10 in three months; and that the author of this paper will never be crowned
king of England. All of these forecasts, and literally millions of others of a similar degree of certainty, are based on the specific
understanding of the values and goals motivating millions of nameless actors.

As noted, the source of thymological experience is our interactions with and observations of other people. It is acquired either directly from observing our fellow men and transacting business with them or indirectly from reading and from hearsay, as well as out of our special experience acquired in previous contacts with the individuals or groups concerned. Such mundane experience is accessible to all who have reached the age of reason and forms the bedrock foundation for forecasting the future conduct of others whose actions will affect their plans. Furthermore, as Mises points out, the use of thymological knowledge in everyday affairs is straightforward:

“Thymology tells no more than that man is driven by various innate instincts, various passions, and various ideas. The anticipating individual tries to set aside those factors that manifestly do not play any concrete role in the concrete case under consideration. Then he chooses among the remaining ones.”

To aid in this task of narrowing down the goals and desires that are likely to motivate the behavior of particular individuals, we resort to the “thymological concept” of “human character. ” The concrete content of the “character” we attribute to a specific individual is based on our direct or indirect knowledge of his past behavior. In formulating our plans, “We assume that this character will not change if no special reasons interfere, and, going a step farther, we even try to foretell how definite changes in conditions will affect his reactions.” It is confidence in our spouse’s “character,” for example, that permits us to leave for work each morning secure in the knowledge that he or she will not suddenly disappear with the children and the family bank account. And our saving and investment plans involve an image of Alan Greenspan’s character that is based on our direct or indirect knowledge of his past actions and utterances. In formulating our intertemporal consumption plans, we are thus led to completely discount or assign a very low likelihood to the possibility that he will either deliberately orchestrate a 10-percent deflation of the money supply or attempt to peg the short-run interest rate at zero percent in the foreseeable future.

Despite reliance on the tool of thymological experience, however, all human understanding of future events remains uncertain, to some degree, for these events are generally a complex resultant of various causal factors operating concurrently. All forecasts of the future, therefore, must involve not only an enumeration of the factors that operate in bringing about the anticipated result but also the weighting of the relative influence of each factor on the outcome. Of the two, the more difficult problem is that of apportioning the proper weights among the various operative factors. Even if the actor accurately and completely identifies all the causal factors involved, the likelihood of the forecast event being realized depends on the actor having solved the weighting problem. The
uncertainty inherent in forecasting, therefore, stems mainly from the intricacy of assigning the correct weights to different actions and the intensity of their effects.

While thymology powerfully, but implicitly, shapes everyone’s understanding of and planning for the future in every facet of life, the thymological method is used deliberately and rigorously by the historian who seeks a specific understanding of the motives underlying the value judgments and choices of the actors whom he judges to have been central to the specific event or epoch he is interested in explaining. Like future events and situations envisioned in the plans of actors, all historical events and the epochs they define are unique and complex outcomes codetermined by numerous human actions and reactions. This is the meaning of Mises’s
statement.

“History is a sequence of changes. Every historical situation has its individuality, its own characteristics that distinguish it from any other situation. The stream of history never returns to a previously occupied point. History is not repetitious.”

It is precisely because history does not repeat itself that thymological experience does not yield certain knowledge of the cause of historical events in the same way as experimentation in the natural sciences. Thus the historian, like the actor, must resort to specific understanding when enumerating the various motives and actions that bear a causal relation to the event in question and when assigning each action’s contribution to the outcome a relative weight. In this task, “Understanding is in the realm of history the equivalent, as it were, of quantitative analysis and measurement.” The historian uses specific understanding to try to gauge the causal “relevance” of each factor to the outcome. But such assessments of relevance do not take the form of objective measurements calculable by statistical techniques; they are expressed in the form of subjective “judgments of relevance” based on thymology. Successful entrepreneurs tend to be those who consistently formulate a superior understanding of the likelihood of future events
based on thymology.

The weighting problem that confronts actors and historians may be illustrated with the following example. The Fed increases the money supply by 5 percent in response to a 20-percent plunge in the Dow Jones Industrial Average—or, perhaps now, the Nasdaq—that ignites fears of a recession and a concomitant increase in the demand for liquidity on the part of households and firms. At the
same time, OPEC announces a 10-percent increase in its members’ quotas and the U.S. Congress increases the minimum wage by 10 percent. In order to answer the question of what the overall impact of these events will be on the purchasing power of money six months hence, specific understanding of individuals’ preferences and expectations is required in order to  weight  and  time  the influence of each of these events on the relationship between the supply of and the demand for money. The ceteris-paribus laws of economic theory are strictly qualitative and only indicate the direction of the effect each of these events has on the purchasing power of money and that the change occurs during a sequential adjustment process so that some time must elapse before the
full effect emerges. Thus the entrepreneur or economist must always supplement economic theory with an act of historical judgment or understanding when attempting to forecast any economic quantity. The economic historian, too, exercises understanding when making judgments of relevance about the factors responsible for the observed movements of the value of money during historical episodes of inflation or deflation.

Rothbard’s contribution to Mises’s method of historical research involves the creation of a guide that mitigates some of the uncertainty associated with formulating judgments of relevance about human motives. According to Rothbard, “It is part of the
inescapable condition of the historian that he must make estimates and judgments about human motivation even though he cannot ground his judgments in absolute and apodictic certainty. ” But the task of assigning motives and weighting their relevance is rendered more difficult by the fact that, in many cases, historical actors, especially those seeking economic gain through the political process, are inclined to deliberately obscure the reasons for their conduct. Generally in these situations, Rothbard points out, “the actor himself tries his best to hide his economic motive and to trumpet his more abstract and ideological concerns.”

Rothbard contends, however, that such attempts to obfuscate or conceal the pecuniary motive for an action by appeals to higher goals are easily discerned and exposed by the historian in those cases “where the causal chain of economic interest to action is simple and direct. ” Thus, for example, when the steel industry lobbies for higher tariffs or reduced quotas, no sane adult, and certainly no competent historian, believes that it is doing so out of its stated concern for the “public interest” or “national security.”
Despite its avowed motives, everyone clearly perceives that the primary motivation of the industry is economic, that is, to restrict foreign competition in order to increase profits. But a problem arises in those cases “when actions involve longer and more complex causal chains. ” Rothbard points to the Marshall Plan as an example of the latter. In this instance, the widely proclaimed motives of the architects of the plan were to prevent starvation in Western European nations and to strengthen their resistance to the allures of Communism. Not a word was spoken about the goal that was also at the root of the Marshall Plan: promoting and subsidizing U.S. export industries. It was only through painstaking research that historians were later able to uncover and assess the relevance of the economic motive at work.

Given the propensity of those seeking and dispensing privileges and subsidies in the political arena to lie about their true motives, Rothbard formulates what he describes as “a theoretical guide which will indicate in advance whether or not a historical action will be predominantly for economic, or for ideological, motives.”39 Now, it is true that Rothbard derives this guide from his overall worldview. The historian’s worldview, however, should not be interpreted as a purely ideological construction or an unconscious reflection of his normative biases. In fact, every historian must be equipped with a worldview—an interrelated set of ideas about the causal relationships governing how the world works—in order to ascertain which facts are relevant in the explanation of a particular historical event. According to Rothbard, “Facts, of course, must be selected and ordered in accordance with judgments of
importance, and such judgments are necessarily tied into the historian’s basic world outlook.”

Specifically, in Mises’s approach to history, the worldview comprises the necessary preconceptions regarding causation with which the historian approaches the data and which are derived from his knowledge of both the aprioristic and natural sciences. According to Mises:

“History is not an intellectual reproduction, but a condensed representation of the past in conceptual terms. The historian does not simply let the events speak for themselves. He arranges them from the aspect of the ideas underlying the formation of the general notions he uses in their presentation. He does not report facts as they happened, but only  relevant  facts. He does not approach the documents without presuppositions, but equipped with the whole apparatus of his age’s scientific knowledge, that is, with all
the teachings of contemporary logic, mathematics, praxeology, and natural science.”

So, for example, the fact that heavy speculation against the German mark accompanied its sharp plunge on foreign-exchange markets is not significant for an Austrian-oriented economic historian seeking to explain the stratospheric rise in commodity prices that characterized the German hyperinflation of the early 1920s. This is because he approaches this event armed with the supply-and-demand theory of money and the purchasing-power-parity theory of the exchange rate.
These “presuppositions” derived from praxeology lead him to avoid any attribution of causal significance to the actions of foreign exchange speculators in accounting for the precipitous decline of the domestic purchasing power of the mark. Instead they direct his attention to the motives of the German Reichs-bank in expanding the money supply. In the same manner, a modern historian investigating the cause and dissemination of bubonic plague in fourteenth-century Europe would presuppose that the blossoming of religious heresy during that period would have no significance for his investigation. Instead he would allow himself to be guided by the conclusions of modern medical science regarding the epidemiology of the disease.

The importance of Rothbard’s theoretical guide is that it adds something completely new to the historian’s arsenal of scientific preconceptions that aids him in making judgments of relevance when investigating the motives of those who promote or oppose specific political actions. The novelty and brilliance of this guide lies in the fact that it is neither a purely aprioristic law like an economic theorem nor an experimentally established “fact” of the natural sciences. Rather it is a sociological generalization grounded on a creative blend of thymo-logical experience and economic theory. At the core of this generalization is the insight
that the State throughout history has been essentially an organization of a segment of the population that forsakes peaceful economic activity to constitute itself as a ruling class. This class makes its living parasitically by establishing a permanent hegemonic or “political” relationship between itself and the productive members of the population. This political relationship permits the rulers to subsist on the tribute or taxes routinely and “legally” expropriated from the income and wealth of the producing class. The latter class is composed of the “subjects” or, in the case of democratic states, the “taxpayers,” who earn their living through the peaceful “economic means” of production and voluntary exchange. In contrast, constituents of the ruling class may be thought of as “tax-consumers” who earn their living through the coercive “political means” of taxation and the sale of
monopoly privileges.

Rothbard argues that economic logic dictates that the king and his courtiers, or the democratic government and its special interest groups, can never constitute more than a small minority of the country’s population—that all States, regardless of their formal
organization, must effectively involve oligarchic rule. The reasons for this are twofold. First, the fundamentally parasitic nature of the relationship between the rulers and the ruled by itself necessitates that the majority of the population engages in productive activity in order to be able to pay the tribute or taxes extracted by the ruling class while still sustaining its own existence. If the ruling class comprised the majority of the population, economic collapse and systemic breakdown would swiftly ensue as the productive class died out. The majoritarian ruling class itself then would either be forced into productive activity or dissolve into internecine warfare aimed at establishing a new and more stable—that is, oligarchic—relationship between rulers and producers.

The second reason why the ruling class tends to be an oligarchy is related to the law of comparative advantage. In a world where human abilities and skills vary widely, the division of labor and specialization pervades all sectors of the economy as well as society as a whole. Thus, not only is it the case that a relatively small segment of the populace possesses a comparative advantage in developing new software, selling mutual funds, or playing professional football, it is also the case that only a fraction of the
population tends to excel at wielding coercive power. Moreover, the law of comparative advantage governs the structure of relationships within as well as between organizations, accounting for the hierarchical structure that we almost invariably observe within individual organizations. Whether we are considering a business enterprise, a chess club, or a criminal gang, an energetic and visionary elite invariably comes to the fore, either formally or informally, to lead and direct the relatively inert majority. This “Iron Law of Oligarchy,” as this internal manifestation of the law of comparative advantage has been dubbed, operates to transform an initially majoritarian democratic government, or even a decentralized republican government, into a tightly centralized State controlled by a ruling elite.

The foregoing analysis leads Rothbard to conclude that the exercise of political power is inherently an oligarchic enterprise. The small minority that excels in wielding political power will tend to coalesce and devote an extraordinary amount of mental energy and other resources to establishing and maintaining a permanent and lucrative hegemonic bond over the productive majority. Accordingly, since politics is the main source of their income, the policies and actions of the members of this oligarchic ruling class will be driven primarily by economic motives. The exploited producing class, in contrast, will not expend nearly as many resources on politics, and their actions in the political arena will not be motivated by economic gain to the same degree, precisely because they are absorbed in earning their livelihoods in their own chosen areas of specialization on the market. As Rothbard explains:

“the ruling class, being small and largely specialized, is motivated to think about its economic interests twenty-four hours a day. The steel manufacturers seeking a tariff, the bankers seeking taxes to repay their government bonds, the rulers seeking a strong state from which to obtain subsidies, the bureaucrats wishing to expand their empire, are all professionals in statism. They are constantly at work trying to preserve and expand their privileges.”

The ruling class, however, confronts one serious and ongoing problem: how to persuade the productive majority, whose tribute or taxes it consumes, that its laws, regulations, and policies are beneficial; that is, that they coincide with “the public interest” or are designed to promote “the common good” or to optimize “social welfare.” Given its minority status, failure to solve this problem exposes the political class to serious consequences. Even passive resistance by a substantial part of the producers, in the form of mass tax resistance, renders the income of the political class and, therefore, its continued existence extremely precarious. More
ominously, attempts to suppress such resistance may cause it to spread and intensify and eventually boil over into an active revolution whose likely result is the forcible ousting of the minority exploiting class from its position of political power. Here is where the intellectuals come in. It is their task to convince the public to actively submit to State rule because it is beneficial to do so, or at least to passively endure the State’s depredations because the alternative is anarchy and chaos. In return for fabricating an ideological cover for its exploitation of the masses of subjects or taxpayers, these “court intellectuals” are rewarded with the power, wealth, and prestige of a junior partnership in the ruling elite. Whereas in pre-industrial times these apologists for State rule were associated with the clergy, in modern times—at least since the Progressive Era in the U.S.—they have
been drawn increasingly from the academy.

Politicians, bureaucrats, and those whom they subsidize and privilege within the economy thus routinely trumpet lofty ideological motives for their actions in order to conceal from the exploited and plundered citizenry their true motive of economic gain. In today’s world, these motives are expressed in the rhetoric of “social democracy” in Europe and that of modern—or welfare-state—liberalism in the United States. In the past, ruling oligarchies have appealed to the ideologies of royal absolutism, Marxism, Progressivism, Fascism, National Socialism, New Deal liberalism, and so on to camouflage their economic goals in advocating a continual aggrandizement of State power. In devising his theoretical guide, then, Rothbard seeks to provide historians with a means of
piercing the shroud of ideological rhetoric and illuminating the true motives underlying the policies and actions of ruling elites throughout history. As Rothbard describes this guide, whenever the would-be or actual proprietors and beneficiaries of the State act, when they form a State, or a centralizing Constitution, when they go to war or create a Marshall Plan or use and increase State power in any way, their primary  motivation is economic: to increase their plunder at the expense of the subject and taxpayer. The ideology that they profess and that is formulated and spread through society by the Court Intellectuals
is merely an elaborate rationalization for their venal economic interests. The ideology is the smoke screen for their loot, the
fictitious clothes spun by the intellectuals to hide the naked plunder of the Emperor. The task of the historian, then, is to penetrate to the essence of the transaction, to strip the ideological garb from the Emperor State and to reveal the economic motive at the heart of the issue.

In characterizing the modern democratic State as essentially a means for coercively redistributing income from producers to politicians, bureaucrats, and special interest groups, Rothbard opens himself up to the charge of espousing a conspiracy theory of economic history. But it is his emphasis on the almost universal propensity of those who employ the political means for economic gain to conceal their true motives with ideological cant that makes him especially susceptible to this charge. Indeed, the Chicago School’s theory of economic regulation and the public choice theory of the Virginia School also portray politicians, bureaucrats, and industries regulated by the State as interested almost exclusively in maximizing their utility in the narrow sense, which in many, if not most, cases involves a maximization of pecuniary gain.  However, economists of both schools are inured against the charge of conspiracy theory because in their applied work they generally eschew a systematic, thymological investigation of the actual motives of those individuals or groups whose actions they are analyzing. Instead, their positivist methodology inclines them to mechanically impute to real actors in concrete historical circumstances a narrowly conceived utility maximization.

Posted in Finances | 1 Comment »

The American Constitution – A Republic if You Can Keep It

Posted by Orrin Woodward on September 28, 2010

Founding Fathers pictureMy adventure with the American election process began much like other young people entering college, not certain who the candidates were, or even what they stood for, I voted with zeal but with little knowledge.  As I gained more experience, through reading newspapers and magazines, I quickly fell into the democratic herd, who spout their surface knowledge regurgitated from the morning newspaper, but understand little if any of why the system operates the way it does.  I conscientiously cast my vote election after election, hoping to maintain my freedoms by the wonderful power of the democratic election process, until a curious thought entered my mind and would not leave.  This uninvited guest, this alien idea would not depart, no matter how much I recited the alleged benefits of democracy.  The thought was simple, but inarguable, if the key to our American freedoms is our democratic elections, if freedom is endangered when Americans neglect this right, how is it that every four years we seem to lose more of our freedoms that our vote was allegedly cast to secure, regardless of which party is elected?  No one seemed to have a satisfactory answer to that question and I quickly realized that we all had the same pat answers espoused to us during our high school indoctrinations.

What if democratic voting isn’t the key to securing freedoms at all?  More pointedly, if it is, why have Americans lost their freedoms at an increasing rate since we inaugurated our full fledged democracy around the turn of the 20th century?  Many times, the worst of errors occur when the key to solving the problem is buried in the unquestioned assumptions of the ruling paradigm.  These questions and others engaged my thoughts as I pondered America’s voting paradox, leading me on to an election epiphany-that it’s not the vote that ensures a people’s freedoms, but a contract between the rulers and the ruled.  Starting with the Magna Carta written to protect English freedoms against a money hungry King John, all the freedoms of the English speaking people’s have been ensured by written contracts between the governed and the governors.  Merely casting your vote, herding into schools and town halls, does not ensure anyone freedom in America.  Even Adolph Hitler, that megalomaniac of power, that dictator of dictators, used the legitimate democratic election process to gain power in Germany.  The more I thought, the more suspicious I became, the constant drum roll of praise beaten into me during my high-school years on the joys of our democratic process, seemed not to square with the facts, leading me to read the Founding Fathers in their own words to learn what they thought of democracy.  To my great surprise, if not downright horror, I learned that democracy was the least favorable form of government in the opinion of nearly all of the Founders.  Even Thomas Jefferson, one of the strongest supporters of the people, was quick to disassociate himself with democracy and stay safely under the republican banner.

If democracy isn’t working in practice, anyone alive during the last 40 years can vouch for this, and the Founding Fathers knew that it didn’t work in theory over 200 years ago, why are American’s constantly bombarded with messaging on the importance of our democratic system?  With taxes increasing yearly, government regulations increasing monthly, the money supply increasing weekly, government bureaucracy increasing daily, government power increasing hourly, our national debt increasing by the minute and our freedoms waning by the second, exactly who is benefiting from this democratic process?  If you answered: Politicians, Political Parties, Big Business, and Wealth Transfer Recipients; you have just qualified for double jeopardy.  Edmund Burke wrote about England in the 18th century, “For us to love our county, our country ought to be lovely.”  I love America and I dream of a lovely America where all races, creeds and colors can come together and unite around the idea of justice and liberty for all.  The Founding Fathers didn’t trust in a democratic election process to ensure their liberties, remember many of the Founding Fathers were lawyers, writing contracts was part of any business partnership, a partnership between the people and the government required a contract to ensure the terms, that contract, written to protect the people from potential government encroachment upon their freedoms was called the American Constitution.

Contracts in business are essential, helping each side of the written agreement maintain his pledge of fidelity to the written terms, but if either side becomes negligent of the contract, abuses can and will occur.  The American people have lost the understanding and intentions of the original contract, sending a clear message to government that the majority to not care to defend their freedoms, most willing to surrender their freedoms for the security of government provisions.  It’s a fools game that must end in the bankruptcy of a once great country, since, if given the choice, the majority of people will choose handouts rather than work.  Only through production can any country maintain its solvency, printing money is not production, borrowing money is not production, only producing goods and services that can be sold on the free market will restore the American Dream.  Able bodied men and women should not be paid to idly sit by while others produce, it’s debilitating in three separate but related ways: to the self esteem of the recipients, to the total production of the country, and to the attitudes of those who are forced to work for others who do not. I don’t read a paragraph on government handouts in our written Constitution, but it’s going to take more than a few of us to read our agreement to set this straight. It’s possible for a group of people, sick and tired of voting every two years only to lose more freedoms, rising up peacefully together, to ensure that government does not encroach upon it written responsibilities.

The majority in a democracy does not have the right to vote its hands into the pockets of any its citizens anymore than an elite has a right to use government power to coerce open the pockets of the majority.  The American Republic must be restored based upon the natural rights and natural law inherent in each person, as the Declaration of Independence has clearly stated.  Further thoughts on our American Constitution can be found in The 5000 Year Leap by W. Cleon Skousen, a must read for any hungry student of our written contract.

Ben Franklin, one of America’s greatest Statesmen, was prophetic when, upon exiting the Constitutional Convention, he was asked what type of government America would be; he answered, “A Republic, if you can keep it.”  We cannot keep our Republic since it was been lost at the turn of the 20th century, but we do have a responsibility to restore it. God Bless, Orrin Woodward

Posted in Faith, Finances, Freedom/Liberty | 5 Comments »

Free Enterprise & Economism – The Difference

Posted by Orrin Woodward on September 27, 2010

Communism Cartoon pictureFree Enterprise describes a society that allows each man or woman the liberty of economic choices, permitting the companies that best serve the customers to survive by the good will engendered.  Government and private coercion are held in check, providing a free environment for the people to thrive based upon their efforts.  Government, in the free enterprise system, plays the role of an umpire, ensuring equality of playing conditions, so that the winning team is the one that serves the customer the best, giving no special deals to any team.  Although free enterprise is the best system in theory and practice, it has rarely been understood in theory and never applied in practice.

Economism describes a society where big business partners with government to provide positive economic arrangements for the chosen few.  Government, instead of playing the role of a neutral umpire, becomes the 12th man on the proverbial football team, helping assist Big Businesses, regardless of the on the field performance.  It’s not hard to find evidence of Economism, simply glancing at any city newspaper, you will read about the latest government “bail out” of XYZ company for the sake of “protecting American jobs.”  Every bail out, in the end, is funded by tax payer dollars, which means the tax payers get to subsidize the wealthy business owner who isn’t competently running his business.  Bail outs cost more to job holders than any protection of jobs the bail out can offer, but that is of secondary importance and not the immediate concern of the politician who is only in office for a limited time anyway.  Government involvement brings in a political element into the economic sphere, damaging the ability of the customers to vote for the business which serves them best.

The sad part of Economism, a confused middle way between Fascism and Free Enterprise, is people will assume Free Enterprise has failed.  In fact, Free Enterprise hasn’t failed in America, it hasn’t been tried.  Any time government involves itself positively in the economy, it begins to play a god-like role, choosing which companies will survive, and which companies will die, even though, it’s less qualified to do so than the millions of customers playing that role in a true Free Enterprise system.   Economism isn’t new, dating back to Egypt under the Pharaohs, if not even earlier, but its modern day examples play god on a much bigger scale.  Look at China, it isn’t communist any longer, but it isn’t free enterprise either; instead, it’s a blend of big business partnered with government, i.e: Economism.  Sadly, China is giving more freedom to business owners in its titular communist system than the United States is giving to business owners in its titular free enterprise system.

What first attracted my attention to this was the astonishing extent to which the rich received special deals from the government.  This is simply unacceptable in a Free Enterprise system.  Many, but not all, of the great fortunes were made by means which were patently unfair, and were known to be so.  Owners of large conglomerates who gained control or at least influence of the State’s machinery, and were using it to their own advantage by way of land-grants, tariff concessions, franchise monopolies and every other known form a law-made privilege, abused the system, all in the name of American Economism.  In view of American justice for all, this was shamefully bad.  Yet on should not blame business owners for exploiting the existing system to their personal advantage, after all, flowing water always follows the riverbed; therefore, true change needs to correct the riverbed, not just punish the water for following the riverbed.  Economism gives the government the unnatural right to intervene in protective tariffs, income taxation, regulation, etc; we should not be shocked that some enterprising, but characterless individuals utilize government intervention for exploitation purposes.  True Free Enterprise has no part and parcel with Economism, knowing that favoritism can never be squared with justice.  On the contrary, free enterprise views government as a neutral umpire in the game of business, while Economism views government as a partner to exploit the masses for the benefit of the elite politicians and business owners.  With Economism reigning as the world-view of nearly all politicians and Big Businesses, what could we expect but a continuous struggle for control of the State machinery, many resorting to pay offs, corruption and the lot to win, all for the right to exploit others with State’s power for one’s personal advantage.

While there are many issues, some listed above on the short sightedness of government intervention in the economy, one of the biggest is the concept called “Destruction of the Commons.”  Government when it ceases to be an umpire and starts playing as a participant in the economy, quickly becomes the battleground of competing groups for control of government’s monopoly of power.  Since citizens have no appeal to any source that isn’t part of the government, gaining control over the political means of power is a major competitive advantage for any big business over its unconnected competitors.  Politicians do not own the government, but only rent their seats for a time, willingly surrendering their influence to the needs of big business in order to ensure their elections.  The politician is thinking of his gain by being elected and isn’t worried about the long term effects of his behavior to the people in general, which perfectly describes the “Destruction of the Commons.”   When you rent a car, you’re not as worried about taking care of it, it isn’t yours and the owner will have to fix those brakes, shocks etc anyway.  If you go faster over bumps in the road, it isn’t the end of the world since it isn’t your car anyway.  Sadly, most politicians think that way about our government, caring little about the national debt, crippling taxation, and economic ruin as that will be someone else’s problem, not theirs.

As a leader, father, and an American, I am asking for my fellow American’s to get educated and informed on our American history and ideals.  What the Founding Fathers envisioned, implemented, and expected, they certainly weren’t perfect and we could learn much from their successes and failures, would be a great start.    There are many books to begin this journey, but I recommend starting with Albert Jay Nock, Our Enemy the State.  It clearly explains why government and business do not mix; even though it is written in the 1930’s, it predicts accurately many of America’s current fiscal dilemmas.  The best way to change the future is to learn from the past and to act in the present. I think its time we start that process. God Bless, Orrin Woodward

Posted in Finances | 3 Comments »

Why does Steve Wynn Trust China Politicians over USA Politicians?

Posted by Orrin Woodward on August 10, 2010

Steven Wynn tells it like it is and every freedom loving American should wake up and take notice.  When billionaires cannot predict the political environment you know you have a train wreck in process in Washington DC.  Watch this video and ponder what our government has done to our money, our savings, our taxes, our futures, and our hope.  We must put Washington DC on a crash diet!  God Bless, Orrin Woodward

<a [youtube=http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=fWacc6L9NoU]

Posted in Finances | Comments Off on Why does Steve Wynn Trust China Politicians over USA Politicians?

Murray Rothbard – Thomas Kuhn’s Paradigm Shifts

Posted by Orrin Woodward on May 3, 2010

I believe an understanding of economics is essential for any leader in any field today.  Without the freedom of action in the economic field, there is a subsequent loss of freedom in any leadership endeavor as well.  Chief Justice Marshall stated, “The power to tax is the power to destroy.”  When governments covet power more than they value liberties, the citizens lose their freedoms, money, and dignity.  If you are a leader or future leader then read the following thoughts by Murray Rothbard in his introduction to his study of Economic History.  Rothbard’s thoughts will start the education process to learn why the American and World Economy is in its current mess.  Do we honestly still believe that government can solve our problems when they cannot even solve their own?  We need a new paradigm that accurately predicted the results of the latest Statist interventions in our economies.  The Austrian Economists are the only school that studies the interventions and accurately predicts the dismal results.  Modern economics is in a dead end street and must admit failure before it can break free of it prevailing Keynesian paradigm.  Every promise by Big Government to solve your problems is actually a power grab to take more of your money and freedoms.  Wake up America before it’s too late!  God Bless, Orrin Woodward

The continual progress, onward-and-upward approach was demolished for me, and should have been for everyone, by Thomas Kuhn’s famed Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Kuhn paid no attention to economics, but instead, in the standard manner of philosophers and historians of science, focused on such ineluctably ‘hard’ sciences as physics, chemistry, and astronomy. Bringing the word ‘paradigm’ into intellectual discourse, Kuhn demolished what I like to call the ‘Whig theory of the history of science’. The Whig theory, subscribed to by almost all historians of science, including economics, is that scientific thought progresses patiently, one year after another developing, sifting, and testing theories, so that science marches onward and upward, each year, decade or generation learning more and possessing ever more correct scientific theories. On analogy with the Whig theory of history, coined in mid-nineteenth century England, which maintained that things are always getting (and therefore must get) better and better, the Whig historian of science, seemingly on firmer grounds than the regular Whig historian, implicitly or explicitly asserts that ‘later is always better’ in any particular scientific discipline.

The Whig historian (whether of science or of history proper) really maintains that, for any point of historical time, ‘whatever was, was right’, or at least better than ‘whatever was earlier’. The inevitable result is a complacent and infuriating Panglossian optimism. In the historiography of economic thought, the consequence is the firm if implicit position that every individual economist, or at least every school of economists, contributed their important mite to the inexorable upward march. There can, then, be no such thing as gross systemic error that deeply flawed, or even invalidated, an entire school of economic thought, much less sent the world of economics permanently astray.

Kuhn, however, shocked the philosophic world by demonstrating that this is simply not the way that science has developed. Once a central paradigm is selected, there is no testing or sifting, and tests of basic assumptions only take place after a series of failures and anomalies in the ruling paradigm has plunged the science into a ‘crisis situation’. One need not adopt Kuhn’s nihilistic philosophic outlook, his implication that no one paradigm is or can be better than any other, to realize that his less than starry-eyed view of science rings true both as history and as sociology.

But if the standard romantic or Panglossian view does not work even in the hard sciences, a fortiori it must be totally off the mark in such a ‘soft science’ as economics, in a discipline where there can be no laboratory testing, and where numerous even softer disciplines such as politics, religion, and ethics necessarily impinge on one’s economic outlook.

There can therefore be no presumption whatever in economics that later thought is better than earlier, or even that all well-known economists have contributed their sturdy mite to the developing discipline. For it becomes very likely that, rather than everyone contributing to an ever-progressing edifice, economics can and has proceeded in contentious, even zig-zag fashion, with later systemic fallacy sometimes elbowing aside earlier but sounder paradigms, thereby redirecting economic thought down a total erroneous or even tragic path. The overall path of economics may be up, or it may be down, over any give time period.

In recent years, economics, under the dominant influence of formalism, positivism and econometrics, and preening itself on being a hard science, has displayed little interest in its own past. It has been intent, as in any ‘real’ science, on the latest textbook or journal article rather than on exploring its own history. After all, do contemporary physicists spend much time poring over eighteenth century optics?

In the last decade or two, however, the reigning Walrasian–Keynesian neoclassical formalist paradigm has been called ever more into question, and a veritable Kuhnian ‘crisis situation’ has developed in various areas of economics, including worry over its methodology. Amidst this situation, the study of the history of thought has made a significant comeback, one which we hope and expect will expand in coming years. For if knowledge buried in paradigms lost can disappear and be forgotten over time, then studying older economists and schools of thought need not be done merely for antiquarian purposes or to examine how intellectual life proceeded in the past. Earlier economists can be studied for their important contributions to forgotten and therefore new knowledge today. Valuable truths can be learned about the content of economics, not only from the latest journals, but from the texts of long-deceased economic thinkers.

Posted in Finances | 2 Comments »

The America We Lost – Dr. Mario Pei

Posted by Orrin Woodward on March 25, 2010

The following article was written in 1952 by an immigrant who came to America to experience the taste of freedom!  Dr. Mario Pei writes a powerful article expressing his thoughts on the difference between America and his homeland, concerned of the growing influence of the State in American’s lives.  I wonder what Dr. Pei would think today if he saw what we have done to America?

For centuries, America has been the bastion of freedom and free enterprise for the oppressed of the world.  Immigrants from nearly every race, creed, and country streamed to America to participate in the Great Experiment, but sadly the American dream is fading.  Under the rhetoric of compassion, security, and order, American citizens have surrendered their freedoms for a pot of porridge.  I read the first 150 years of American history in vain to find anyone who left their native lands seeking a secure government package including health care, social security, and a good job.  Government exploiters cannot secure anything to anyone without first un-securing funds from producers.  Anyone who is willing to work/lead, pay his/her taxes, and accept responsibility needs to understand that YOU will be taxed into oblivion to support others,  others that are fully capable of supporting themselves like Americans have done for centuries, without State interventions.

We have reached a tipping point in American history where the exploiters have nearly matched the producers.  It is a Law of Human Nature that people will do the least amount of work to satisfy their needs.  If Big Government will take from the producers and give to the exploiters, then America will no longer be the Land of Opportunity, but the Land of the Exploiters.  True Opportunities are only available to producers who are willing to think, risk, and sweat to accomplish the victory.  Exploiters loathe risk, sweat, and failure and would rather think about how to siphon off production from producers.  I believe strongly in charity for those truly in need, but do we need Big Brother to tell us to help our neighbor?  Why allow Big Government to play a twisted version of Robin Hood, stealing from producers, grasping for power, and robbing the self-respect from Americans by giving handouts instead of hand ups?

America is at the crossroads, one road leading to further exploitation & State Tyranny, the other road leading us back to production & liberty.  Do not surrender lightly the freedoms bought and purchased with our fore-fathers/fore-mothers blood, sweat, and tears.  God Bless, Orrin Woodward
Dr. Mario Pei, who came to this country from Italy in 1908, is Professor of Romance Philology at Columbia University in New York. He is the author of several distinguished books and numerous magazine articles. The Foundation was given special permission by the Saturday Evening Post to reprint the above article. Copyright 1952 by The Curtis Publishing Company

When I first came to America, many years ago, I learned a new meaning of the word “Liberty”—freedom from government.

I did not learn a new meaning for “democracy.” The European country from which I came, Italy, was at that time as “democratic” as America. It was a constitutional monarchy, with a parliament, free and frequent elections, lots of political parties and plenty of freedom of religion, speech, press, and assembly.

But my native country was government-ridden. A vast bureaucracy held it in its countless tentacles. Regardless of the party or coalition of parties that might be in power at the moment, the government was everywhere. Wherever one looked, one saw signs of the ever present government: in the uniforms of numberless royal, rural, and municipal policemen, soldiers, officers, gold-braided functionaries of all sorts. You could not take a step without government intervention.

Many industries and businesses were government owned and government run railroads, telegraphs, salt, and tobacco among them. No agreement, however trivial, was legal unless written on government-stamped paper. If you stepped out of the city into the country and came back with a ham, a loaf of bread, or a bottle of wine, you had to stop at the internal-revenue barriers and pay duty to the government, and so did the farmers who brought in the city’s food supply every morning. No business could be started or run without the official sanction of a hundred bureaucrats.

Young people did not dream of going into business for themselves; they dreamed of a modest but safe government job, where they would have tenure, security, and a pitiful pension at the end of their plodding careers. There was grinding taxation to support the many government functions and the innumerable public servants. Everybody hated the government—not just the party in power, but the government itself. They had even coined a phrase, “It’s raining—thief of a government!” as though even the evils of nature were the government’s fault. Yet, I repeat, the country was democratically run, with all the trappings of a many-party system and all the freedoms of which we in America boast today.

America in those days made you open your lungs wide and inhale great gulps of freedom-laden air, for here was one additional freedom—freedom from government.

The government was conspicuous by its very absence. There were no men in uniform, save occasional cops and firemen, no visible bureaucrats, no stifling restrictions, no government monopolies. It was wonderful to get used to the American system: to learn that a contract was valid if written on the side of a house; that you could move not only from the city to the country but from state to state and never be asked what your business was or whether you had anything to declare; that you could open and conduct your own business, provided it was a legitimate one, without government interference; that you could go from one end of the year to the other and never have contact with the national government, save for the cheery postman who delivered your mail with a speed and efficiency unknown today; that there were no national taxes, save hidden excises and import duties that you did not even know you paid.

In that horse-and-buggy America, if you made an honest dollar, you could pocket it or spend it without having to figure what portion of it you “owed” the government or what possible deductions you could allege against that government’s claims. You did not have to keep books and records of every bit of income and expenditure or run the risk of being called a liar and a cheat by someone in authority.

Above all, the national ideal was not the obscure security of a government job, but the boundless opportunity that all Americans seemed to consider their birthright. Those same Americans loved their government then. It was there to help, protect, and defend them, not to restrict, befuddle, and harass them. At the same time, they did not look to the government for a livelihood or for special privileges and hand­outs. They were independent men in the full sense of the word.

Foreign-born citizens have been watching with alarm the gradual Europeanization of America over the past twenty years. They have seen the growth of the familiar European-style government octopus, along with the vanishing of the American spirit of freedom and opportunity and its replacement by a breathless search for “security” that is doomed to defeat in advance in a world where nothing, not even life itself, is secure.

Far more than the native born, they are in a position to make comparisons. They see that America is fast becoming a nineteenth century-model European country. They are asked to believe that this is progress. But they know from bitter experience that it just isn’t so.

Milk on the Doorstep

“It is remarkable,” comments George Schwartz, an English writer, in an article in The New York Times Magazine, “how many people can see no sense in the existing order of Western society, the easiest criticism of which is that it is not order but disorder. With the milk on the doorstep every morning, the free economy is denounced as unplanned, uncoordinated, and chaotic.”

It is a valid observation. There are countries—notably Russia—that have all the necessary material resources but still can’t get the morning milk to the doorstep. Their society’s system of production and distribution is fully ordered, carefully blueprinted by government experts. But they have the plan and no milk while we have the milk and no plan.

The fact is, of course, that our economy does not exist in disorder. In the milk business, to take the everyday example mentioned by Mr. Schwartz, there are literally thousands of individuals—farmers, truckers, processors, and salesmen, and the thousands more who are their suppliers—who make the major or minor decisions that get the milk to the doorstep, and earn a profit in the process. No group of government experts could equal the input of knowledge, industry, flexibility, and efficiency that is the combined total contribution of all of these individuals.

Posted in Finances, Freedom/Liberty | Comments Off on The America We Lost – Dr. Mario Pei

American Freedom & Austria’s Experience with Totalitarianism

Posted by Orrin Woodward on March 10, 2010

Kitty Werthmann pictureFreedom isn’t free and people who treat it lightly are likely to lose it.  Throughout the history of mankind, people have yearned to be free from the yoke of tyranny and oppression.  Freedom is a blip on the screen of a long history of corruption and tyrannical power grabs.  History is a fascinating subject for so many reasons, but the part that strikes me most profoundly is the inability for mankind to learn from it.  The names change, the countries change, but the principles of oppression are attempted again and again, dressed in a new garb. 

The following article is by Kitty Werthmann, who grew up in Austria during the Nazi takeover and is a chilling portrayal of lost freedoms.  Her story is personal, but aligns with the economic and historical books that I have read covering this historical period.  Freedom can be lost in a day or gradually eroded by increased government involvement in the personal lives of its citizens.  Friedrich Von Hayek’s book, The Road to Serfdom should be required reading for all high school graduates to prepare them against totalitarian techniques.

Leadership is not done in a vacuum, meaning without freedom there is no leadership.  If people have power over you, they don’t use leadership, but will resort to force as it is much easier to compel than influence.  This principle is as old as the history of man, but doesn’t seem to sink in easily if at all.  I encourage everyone to read and think through Kitty’s personal story.  Ideas do have consequences and the ideas you do not know still have can have consequences in your life.  I believe American leaders have a responsibility to speak about the precious gift of freedom as leadership is pointless in a totalitarian system.  Patrick Henry said it right nearly 250 years ago, “Give me liberty or give me death.”  The Founding Fathers understood that freedom was non-negotiable and we must learn this lesson before it is to late.  God Bless, Orrin Woodward

America truly is the  Greatest Country in the World. Don’t Let Freedom Slip  Away 
 By: Kitty  Werthmann


What I  am about to tell you is something you’ve probably never heard  or will ever read in history books. 
  
I believe that I am an eyewitness to history.  I cannot  tell you that Hitler took Austria by tanks and guns; it would  distort history.  We elected him by a landslide – 98% of  the vote..  I’ve never read that in any American publications.  Everyone thinks that Hitler just rolled in  with his tanks and took Austria by force.  
 
 In 1938,   Austria was in deep Depression.  Nearly one-third of our  workforce was unemployed.  We had 25% inflation and 25%  bank loan interest rates.  
 Farmers and  business people were declaring bankruptcy daily.  Young  people were going from house to house begging for food.   Not that they didn’t want to work; there simply weren’t any  jobs.  My mother was a Christian woman and believed in  helping people in need.  Every day we cooked a big kettle  of soup and baked bread to feed those poor, hungry people –  about 30 daily.
 

The Communist  Party and the National Socialist Party were fighting each  other.  Blocks and blocks of cities like Vienna , Linz ,  and Graz were destroyed.  The people became desperate and  petitioned the government to let them decide what kind of  government they wanted.
 
We looked to  our neighbor on the north, Germany , where Hitler had been in  power since 1933.  We had been told that they didn’t have  unemployment or crime, and they had a high standard of  living.  Nothing was ever said about persecution of any  group — Jewish or otherwise.  We were led to believe  that everyone was happy. We wanted the same way of life  in Austria . We were promised that a vote for Hitler would  mean the end of unemployment and help for the family.   Hitler also said that businesses would be assisted, and  farmers would get their farms back.  Ninety-eight percent  of the population voted to annex Austria to Germany and have Hitler for our ruler.

We were  overjoyed, and for three days we danced in the streets and had  candlelight parades.  The new government opened up big  field kitchens and everyone was fed.  
 After the  election, German officials were appointed, and like a miracle,  we suddenly had law and order.  Three or four weeks  later, everyone was employed.  The government made sure  that a lot of work was created through the Public Work  Service.  
   
Hitler  decided we should have equal rights for women.  Before  this, it was a custom that married Austrian women did not work  outside the home.  An able-bodied husband would be looked  down on if he couldn’t support his family.  Many women in  the teaching profession were elated that they could retain the  jobs they previously had been required to give up for  marriage.
 
 
Hitler  Targets Education – Eliminates Religious Instruction for  Children: 
 


Our  education was nationalized.  I attended a very good  public school.  The population was predominantly  Catholic, so we had religion in our schools. The day we  elected Hitler (March 13, 1938), I walked into my schoolroom  to find the crucifix replaced by Hitler’s picture hanging next  to a Nazi flag. Our teacher, a very devout woman, stood up and  told the class we wouldn’t pray or have religion  anymore.  Instead, we sang “Deutschland, Deutschland,  Uber Alles,” and had physical education.

Sunday became  National Youth Day with compulsory attendance.  Parents  were not pleased about the sudden change in curriculum.   They were told that if they did not send us, they would  receive a stiff letter of warning the first time.  The  second time they would be fined the equivalent of $300, and  the third time they would be subject to jail.  The first  two hours consisted of political indoctrination.  The  rest of the day we had sports.  As time went along, we  loved it.  Oh, we had so much fun and got our sports  equipment free.  We would go home and gleefully tell our  parents about the wonderful time we had.

My mother was  very unhappy.  When the next term started, she took me  out of public school and put me in a convent.  I told her  she couldn’t do that and she told me that someday when I grew  up, I would be grateful. There was a very good  curriculum, but hardly any fun – no sports, and no political  indoctrination.  I hated it at first but felt I could  tolerate it.  Every once in a while, on holidays, I went  home.  I would go back to my old friends and ask what was  going on and what they were doing.  Their loose lifestyle  was very alarming to me.  They lived without  religion.  By that time unwed mothers were glorified for  having a baby for Hitler.  It seemed strange to me that  our society changed so suddenly.  As time went along, I  realized what a great deed my mother did so that I wasn’t  exposed to that kind of humanistic philosophy.

Equal Rights  Hits Home: 
  


In  1939, the war started and a food bank was established.   All food was rationed and could only be purchased using food  stamps.  At the same time, a full-employment law was  passed which meant if you didn’t work, you didn’t get a ration  card, and if you didn’t have a card, you starved to death. Women who stayed home to raise their families didn’t have any  marketable skills and often had to take jobs more suited for  men.

Soon after  this, the draft was implemented.  It was  compulsory for young people, male and female, to give one  year to the labor corps.  During the day, the girls  worked on the farms, and at night they returned to their barracks for military training just like the boys.  They  were trained to be anti-aircraft gunners and participated in  the signal corps.  After the labor corps, they were not  discharged but were used in the front lines.  When I go  back to Austria to visit my family and friends, most of these  women are emotional cripples because they just were not  equipped to handle the horrors of combat.  Three months  before I turned 18, I was severely injured in an air raid  attack.  I nearly had a leg amputated, so I was spared  having to go into the labor corps and into military  service.

Hitler  Restructured the Family Through Daycare:  


When the  mothers had to go out into the work force, the government  immediately established child care centers.  You could  take your children ages 4 weeks to school age and leave them  there around-the-clock, 7 days a week, under the total care of  the government.  The state raised a whole generation of  children..  There were no motherly women to take care of  the children, just people highly trained in child  psychology.  By this time, no one talked about equal  rights.  We knew we had been had.

Health Care  and Small Business Suffer Under Government  Controls: 
 


Before  Hitler, we had very good medical care.  Many  American doctors trained at the University of Vienna …  After Hitler, health care was socialized, free for  everyone.  Doctors were salaried by the government.   The problem was, since it was free, the people were going to  the doctors for everything. When the good doctor arrived at  his office at 8 a.m., 40 people were already waiting and, at  the same time, the hospitals were full.  If you needed  elective surgery, you had to wait a year or two for your  turn.  There was no money for  research as it was poured into socialized medicine.  Research at the medical schools literally  stopped, so the best doctors left Austria and  emigrated to other countries.  
   
As  for healthcare, our tax rates went up to 80% of our  income.  Newlyweds immediately received a  $1,000 loan from the government to establish a  household.  We had big programs for families.  All day care and education were free.  High schools were  taken over by the government and college tuition was subsidized.  Everyone was entitled to free handouts, such  as food stamps, clothing, and housing.

We had another  agency designed to monitor business.  My  brother-in-law owned a restaurant that had square tables.  Government officials told him he had to replace  them with round tables because people might bump themselves on  the corners.  Then they said he had to have additional  bathroom facilities. It was just a small dairy business with a  snack bar.  He couldn’t meet all the demands.  Soon,  he went out of business.  If the government owned the  large businesses and not many small ones existed, it could be  in control.

We had consumer  protection.  We were told how to shop and what to  buy.  Free enterprise was essentially abolished.  We  had a planning agency specially designed for farmers.   The agents would go to the farms, count the live-stock, then  tell the farmers what to produce, and how to produce  it.

“Mercy  Killing” Redefined: 
  


In  1944, I was a student teacher in a small village in the Alps  .  The villagers were surrounded by mountain passes  which, in the winter, were closed off with snow, causing  people to be isolated.  So people intermarried and  offspring were sometimes retarded.  When I arrived, I was  told there were 15 mentally retarded adults, but they were all  useful and did good manual work.  I knew one, named  Vincent, very well.  He was a janitor of the  school.  One day I looked out the window and saw Vincent  and others getting into a van.  I asked my superior where  they were going.  She said to an institution where the  State Health Department would teach them a trade, and to read  and write.  The families were required to sign papers  with a little clause that they could not visit for 6  months.  They were told visits would interfere with the  program and might cause homesickness.

As time passed,  letters started to dribble back saying these people died a  natural, merciful death.  The villagers were not  fooled.  We suspected what was happening.  Those  people left in excellent physical health and all died within 6  months.  We called this euthanasia.

The Final  Steps – Gun Laws:

Next came  gun registration.. People were  getting injured by guns.  Hitler said that the real way  to catch criminals (we still had a few) was by matching serial  numbers on guns.  Most citizens were law abiding and dutifully marched to the police station to register their  firearms.  Not long after-wards, the police said that it was best for everyone to turn in their guns.  The  authorities already knew who had them, so it was futile not to comply voluntarily.

No more  freedom of speech. Anyone who said  something against the government was taken away.  We knew many people who were arrested, not only Jews, but also priests  and ministers who spoke up. 

Totalitarianism  didn’t come quickly, it took 5 years from 1938 until  1943, to realize full dictatorship in Austria.  Had it happened overnight, my countrymen  would have fought to the last breath.  Instead, we  had creeping gradualism.  Now, our only  weapons were broom handles.  The whole idea sounds almost  unbelievable that the state, little by little eroded our  freedom.

After World  War II, Russian troops occupied Austria .  Women  were raped, preteen to elderly.  The press never wrote  about this either.  When the Soviets left in 1955, they  took everything that they could, dismantling whole factories  in the process.  They sawed down whole orchards of fruit,  and what they couldn’t destroy, they burned..  We called  it The Burned Earth. Most of the population barricaded  themselves in their houses.  Women hid in their cellars  for 6 weeks as the troops mobilized.  Those who couldn’t,  paid the price.

There is a monument in Vienna today,  dedicated to those women who were massacred by the  Russians.  This is an eye witness account.  
 “It’s true..those of us  who sailed past the Statue of Liberty came to a country of  unbelievable freedom and opportunity.

 America Truly is  the Greatest Country in the World. Don’t Let Freedom Slip  Away  “After America , There  is No Place to Go”

Posted in Finances, Freedom/Liberty | Comments Off on American Freedom & Austria’s Experience with Totalitarianism